Message-ID: <15996497.1075843090144.JavaMail.evans@thyme> Date: Mon, 29 Nov 1999 12:02:00 -0800 (PST) From: levine@haas.berkeley.edu To: e201b-1@haas.berkeley.edu, e201b-2@haas.berkeley.edu Subject: Fwd: FRBSF: Economic Letter (01/29/1999) Mime-Version: 1.0 Content-Type: text/plain; charset=us-ascii Content-Transfer-Encoding: 7bit X-From: "David I. Levine" X-To: e201b-1@haas.berkeley.edu, e201b-2@haas.berkeley.edu X-cc: X-bcc: X-Folder: \Jeff_Dasovich_Dec2000\Notes Folders\Mba--macroeconomics X-Origin: DASOVICH-J X-FileName: jdasovic.nsf > > > Dr. Levine: > I found this article quite useful in understanding the evolution of > the U.S. monetary policy. Do you think this is appropriate for the > entire class? > Thanks, > > -Jay Iyer > > http://www.frbsf.org/econrsrch/wklyltr/wklyltr99/el99-04.html > > > Economic Research > > > > > > > FRBSF Economic Letter > > > > > > > Number 99-04; January 29, 1999 > > > > > > ---------- > > <../index.htm>Economic Letter Index > > The Goals of U.S. Monetary Policy > * The evolution of the Fed's legislative mandate > * The debate about the Fed's current mandate > * References > > ---------- > The Federal Reserve has seen its legislative mandate for monetary policy > change several times since its founding in 1913, when macroeconomic policy as > such was not clearly understood. The most recent revisions were in 1977 and > 1978, and they require the Fed to promote both price stability and full > employment. The past changes in the mandate appear to reflect both economic > events in the U.S. and advances in understanding how the economy functions. > In the twenty years since the Fed's mandate was last changed, there have been > further important economic developments as well as refinements in economic > thought, and these raise the issue of whether to modify the goals for U.S. > monetary policy once again. Indeed, a number of other countries--notably > those that adopted the Euro as a common curency at the start of this > year--have accepted price stability as the new primary goal for their > monetary policies. > > In this Letter, we spell out the evolution of the legislation governing U.S. > monetary policy goals and summarize the debate about whether they could be > improved. > > The evolution of the Fed's legislative mandate > > The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 did not incorporate any macroeconomic goals > for monetary policy, but instead required the Fed to "provide an elastic > currency." This meant that the Fed should help the economy avoid the > financial panics and bank runs that plagued the 19th century by serving as a > "lender of last resort," which involved making loans directly to depository > institutions through the discount windows of the Reserve Banks. During this > early period, most of the actions of monetary policy that affected the macro > economy were determined by the U.S. government's adherence to the gold > standard. > > The trauma of the Great Depression, coupled with the insights of Keynes > (1936), led to an acknowledgment of the obligation of the federal government > to prevent recessions. The Employment Act of 1946 was the first legislative > statement of these macroeconomic policy goals. Although it did not > specifically mention the Federal Reserve, it required the federal government > in general to foster "conditions under which there will be afforded useful > employment opportunities ... for those able, willing, and seeking to work, > and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power." > > The Great Inflation of the 1970s was the next major U.S. economic > dislocation. This problem was addressed in a 1977 amendment to the Federal > Reserve Act, which provided the first explicit recognition of price stability > as a national policy goal. The amended Act states that the Fed "shall > maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate > with the economy's long run potential to increase production, so as to > promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and > moderate long-term interest rates." The goals of "stable prices" and > "moderate long-term interest rates" are related because nominal interest > rates are boosted by a premium over real rates equal to expected future > inflation. Thus, "stable prices" will typically produce long-term interest > rates that are "moderate." > > The objective of "maximum" employment remained intact from the 1946 > Employment Act; however, the interpretation of this term may have changed > during the intervening 30 years. Immediately after World War II, when > conscription and price controls had produced a high-pressure economy with > very low unemployment in the U.S., some perhaps believed that the goal of > "maximum" employment could be taken in its mathematical sense to mean the > highest possible level of employment. However, by the second half of the > 1970s, it was well understood that some "frictional" unemployment, which > involves the search for new jobs and the transition between occupations, is a > necessary accompaniment to the proper functioning of the economy in the long > run. > > This understanding went hand in hand in the latter half of the 1970s with a > general acceptance of the Natural Rate Hypothesis, which implies that if > policy were to try to keep employment above its long-run trend permanently > or, equivalently, the unemployment rate below its natural rate, then > inflation would be pushed higher and higher. Policy can temporarily reduce the > unemployment rate below its natural rate or, equivalently, boost employment > above its long-run trend. However, persistently attempting to maintain > "maximum" employment that is above its long-run level would not be consistent > with the goal of stable prices. > > Thus, in order for maximum employment and stable prices to be mutually > consistent goals, maximum employment should be interpreted as meaning maximum > sustainable employment, referred to also as "full employment." Moreover, > although the Fed has little if any influence on the long-run level of > employment, it can attempt to smooth out short-run fluctuations. Accordingly, > promoting full employment can be interpreted as a countercyclical monetary > policy in which the Fed aims to smooth out the amplitude of the business > cycle. > > This interpretation of the Fed's mandate was later confirmed in the > Humphrey-Hawkins legislation. As its official title--the Full Employment and > Balanced Growth Act of 1978--clearly implies, this legislation mandates the > federal government generally to "...promote full employment and production, > increased real income, balanced growth, a balanced Federal budget, adequate > productivity growth, proper attention to national priorities, achievement of > an improved trade balance . . . and reasonable price stability..." (italics > added). > > Besides clarifying the general goal of full employment, the Humphrey-Hawkins > Act also specified numerical definitions or targets. The Act specified two > initial goals: an unemployment rate of 4% for full employment and a CPI > inflation rate of 3% for price stability. These were only "interim" goals to > be achieved by 1983 and followed by a further reduction in inflation to 0% by > 1988; however, the disinflation policies during this period were not to > impede the achievement of the full-employment goal. Thereafter, the timetable > to achieve or maintain price stability and full employment was to be defined > by each year's Economic Report of the President. > > The debate about the Fed's current mandate > > The Fed then has two main legislated goals for monetary policy: promoting > full employment and promoting stable prices. With this mandate, the Fed has > helped foster the exceptional performance of the U.S. economy during the past > decade. Still, some have argued that the Fed's mandate could be improved, > especially in looking ahead to future attempts to maintain or > institutionalize recent low inflation. Much discussion has centered on two > topics: the transparency of the goals and their dual nature. > > The transparency of goals refers to the extent to which the objectives of > monetary policy are clearly defined and can be easily and obviously > understood by the public. The goal of full employment will never be very > transparent because it is not directly observed but only estimated by > economists with limited precision. For example, the 1997 Economic Report of > the President (which has authority in this matter from the Humphrey-Hawkins > Act) gives a range of 5 to 6% for the unemployment rate consistent with full > employment, with a midpoint of 5.5%. Research suggests that there is a very > wide range of uncertainty around any estimate of the natural rate, with one > prominent study finding a 95% probability that it falls in the wide range of > 4 to 7-1/2 % (see Walsh 1998). > > Price stability as a goal is also subject to some ambiguity. Recent economic > analysis has uncovered systematic biases, say, on the order of 1 percentage > point, in the CPI's measurement of inflation (see Motley 1997). In this case, > actual price stability would be consistent with measured inflation of 1%. In > addition, at any point in time, different price indexes register different > rates of inflation. Over the past year, for example, the CPI has risen about > 1-1/2%, while the GDP price index has risen about 1%. Still, a transparent > price stability goal could be specified as a precise numerical growth rate > (or range) for a particular index (which could take into account any biases). > However, economists have also suggested other ways to enhance the > transparency of policy. For example, publishing medium-term inflation > forecasts might help to clarify the direction of policy (Rudebusch and Walsh > 1998). Because the central bank has some control over inflation in the medium > term, its forecasts would contain an indication of where it wanted inflation > to go. > > A second recent proposed modification to the Fed's goals involves focusing to > a larger extent on price stability and de-emphasizing business cycle > stabilization. Some economists have argued that having dual goals will lead > to an inflation bias despite the Fed's best attempts to control inflation. > This argument stresses that the temptation to engineer gains in output in the > short run will overcome the central bank's desire to control inflation in the > long run. As a result of elevated inflation expectations of the public, > inflation will end up being higher than the central bank intended, despite > its best efforts. This "time-inconsistency" argument, as economists call it, > coupled with the pain incurred in the 1970s as inflation skyrocketed and in > the early 1980s as inflation was reduced to moderate levels, persuaded many > that the primary goal of the central bank should be to stabilize prices. > > This view is embodied in the charter for the central bank in the new European > Monetary Union: "The primary objective of the European System of Central > Banks is to maintain price stability. Without prejudice to the objective of > price stability, the ESCB shall support the general economic policies in the > Community." Among these latter policies are "a high level of employment" and > "a balanced development of economic activities." > > Economists remain divided on the importance of the time inconsistency problem > and on the need to put primary emphasis on price stability at the expense of > output stabilization. Some stress the fact that the central bank is the only > entity that can guarantee price stability, and that this goal is not likely > to be attained for long unless price stability is designated as the primary > goal. Others find the arguments for time inconsistency implausible because > policymakers, who are aware of the arguments about an inflationary bias and > see the implications for inflation, can conduct policy without an > inflationary bias (McCallum 1995). Still others argue that the abdication of > other goals is irresponsible (Fuhrer 1997). Also, a good deal of empirical > research using simulations of models of the U.S. economy suggests that a > focus on dual goals can reduce the variance of real GDP (i.e., smooth the > business cycle) while achieving an inflation goal as well (Rudebusch and > Svensson 1998). > > While these issues are not yet resolved, the experience of the past two > decades provides some support to those who think dual goals that lack > transparency can function successfully. It is true that some countries around > the world have reduced inflation over this period while putting primary > emphasis on explicit inflation targeting. But at the same time, with its > current legislative mandate, the Fed also has had success in reducing > inflation, while maintaining the flexibility of responding to business cycle > conditions. > > John P. Judd > Vice President and Associate > Director of Research > > Glenn D. Rudebusch > Research Officer > References > > Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. 1997. "Central Bank Independence and Inflation Targeting: > Monetary Policy Paradigms for the Next Millennium?" New England Economic > Review January/February, pp.20-36. > Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and > Money. Harcourt, Brace, and Company: New York. > > McCallum, Bennett. 1995. "Two Fallacies Concerning Central Bank > Independence." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, vol. 85, no. 2 > (May), pp. 207-211. > > Motley, Brian. 1997. "Bias in the CPI: Roughly Wrong or Precisely Wrong." > <../el97-16.htm>FRBSF Economic Letter<../el97-16.htm> 97-16 (May 23). > > Rudebusch, Glenn D., and Lars E.O. Svensson. 1998. > "Policy Rules for > Inflation Targeting." NBER Working Paper 6512. > > Rudebusch Glenn D., and Carl E. Walsh. 1998. "U.S. Inflation Targeting: Pro > and Con." <../wklyltr98/el98-18.htm>FRBSF Economic > Letter<../wklyltr98/el98-18.htm> 98-18 (May 29). > > Walsh, Carl E. 1998. "The Natural Rate, NAIRU, and Monetary Policy." > <../wklyltr98/el98-28.htm>FRBSF Economic Letter > <../wklyltr98/el98-28.htm>98-28 (September 18). > > ---------- > Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of > the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board > of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Editorial comments may be > addressed to the editor or to the author. Mail comments to: >> >> Research Department >> Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco >> P.O. Box 7702 >> San Francisco, CA 94120 > > David I. Levine Associate professor Haas School of Business ph: 510/642-1697 University of California fax: 510/643-1420 Berkeley CA 94720-1900 email: levine@haas.berkeley.edu http://web.haas.berkeley.edu/www/levine/